The Antebellum Tariff: Different Products or Competing Sources? A Comment on Irwin and Temin

Similar documents
Mehdi Mahbub CEO & Chief Consultant, Best Sourcing Founder, RMG Bangladesh GLOBAL TRENDS IN THE GARMENT SECTOR AND OPPORTUNITIES FOR BANGLADESH

China is simply having their comeback.

Overview of the Global Textile Industry

1. Global Production and Trade of Raw Jute and Jute Goods: A Low Level Equilibrium Market 2. Production and Export of Jute and Jute Goods in Banglades

Growth and Changing Directions of Indian Textile Exports in the aftermath of the WTO

Assessment Schedule 2016 Economics: Demonstrate understanding of producer choices using supply (90985)

-2- profit margins as a consequence of the relentless penetration of imports in the domestic market. Consider these shocking statistics: From 1968 to

Market Analysis. Summary

This is a licensed product of Ken Research and should not be copied

REPUBLIC OF RWANDA MINISTRY OF TRADE, INDUSTRY AND EAC AFFAIRS

GROWTH AND PERFORMANCE OF INDIAN JUTE INDUSTRY

ALASKA GROSS STATE PRODUCT

THE SEGMENTATION OF THE ROMANIAN CLOTHING MARKET

A STUDY ON GARMENT EXPORTERS PERCEPTION ON TECHNOLOGY UPGRADATION IN TIRUPUR CITY

2. The US Apparel and Footwear Market Size by Personal Consumption Expenditure,

US Denim Jeans Market Report

U.S. Census Bureau Carpet and Rugs MA314Q(09) - 1 Issued June 2010

Fashion Designers

Current cotton fiber market in Russia

Chapman Ranch Lint Cleaner Brush Evaluation Summary of Fiber Quality Data "Dirty" Module 28 September 2005 Ginning Date

INDUSTRY OVERVIEW. No. of establishments 117 (manufacturing) March ,257 (import and export) December 2000

Statement of David Page Vice President Dimensions, Inc. 641 McKnight Street Reading, PA 19601

Sampling Process in garment industry

The WWI Trade Shock and the Boom of Textile Industry in China

IWTO Market Information Review and Outlook

Global market review of denim and jeanswear forecasts to edition (revised and updated)

Impacts of Multi-Fiber Arrangement Removal on Textile & Cotton Trade

MNPE In Collaboration with. Karnataka State Open University. Manasagangotri, Mysore-6. Syllabus Certificate in Fashion Designing

SALES (EURO 7.94 BLN) AND TRADE SURPLUS (EURO 2.3 BLN) FOR

The Lesotho Textile and Garment Industry Opportunities

Overview of Taiwan Textile Industry 2013

Textile Per Capita Consumption

China Home Textile Industry Overview,

Kadgee Clothing. Scenario and requirement

About the Report. Booming Women Apparel Market in India

IMPACT OF AGOA ON LESOTHO TEXTILE INDUSTRY

Italy. Eyewear Key Figures 2015

period? The essay begins by outlining the divergence in opinion amongst scholars as to the

Effective Machine Layout to Minimize the CM for T-shirt & Polo-shirt

Jute in South Asia. A K M Rezaur Rahman*

COTTON VERSUS SYNTHETICS THE CONSUMER PERSPECTIVE. A. Terhaar Cotton Council International, Washington, D.C., USA

Risks to the Mexican Textile Industry from trade liberalization effects of the end of. the Multi-Fiber Agreement. By Lenami Godinez. For: Dr.

Global Fast Fashion Market with Focus on The United States: Size, Trends & Forecast ( ) June 2016

ADVANCED DIPLOMA OF BUSINESS BSB60215

THIS REPORT CONTAINS ASSESSMENTS OF COMMODITY AND TRADE ISSUES MADE BY USDA STAFF AND NOT NECESSARILY STATEMENTS OF OFFICIAL U.S.

Louis Vuitton in India

THE INDONESIAN TEXTILE AND CLOTHING OUTLOOK

THE CHANGING WORLD TEXTILE MARKET

Indian Cotton Textile Consumption in the Post-MFA Era

What is econometrics? INTRODUCTION. Scope of Econometrics. Components of Econometrics

THE ARTIST S RESALE RIGHT: DEROGATION FOR DECEASED ARTISTS CONSULTATION SUMMARY OF RESPONSES

Tailoring to Perfection Enterprise Model in Apparel Sector

A Study On Growth Of Textile Industries In India With Pre And Post Liberalization Period

Dutch Circular Textiles Platform

Thailand s Jewelry Industry Overview 2016

Manufacture of Shirt (top) and Skirts

Problem of Micro Enterprises in India- A Case Study of Firozabad Bangle

Stretching or Shrinking? The Textile and Clothing Industries in Canada

Session 10. Sourcing and Supplier Management Practices

Australian Archaeology

IMAGES Business of Fashion

6. Leather Footwear. Fig. 1 Japan s leather footwear imports

Because you re worth it: women s daily hair care routines in contemporary Britain

The Uruguay Round Agreement: Implications for Pakistan s Textiles and Clothing Sector

Higher National Unit Specification. General information for centres. Fashion: Commercial Design. Unit code: F18W 34

THE EXPORT GROWTH AND REVEALED COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE OF THAILAND TO INDIA S JEWELRY SECTOR

APPENDIX I. ANALYSIS OF THE CURRENT STATE

International Journal of Fiber and Textile Research. ISSN Original Article NEW POSSIBILITIES IN KHADI DESIGNING

Changing Revealed Comparative Advantage: A Case Study of Footwear Industry of Pakistan

Brand Icons and Brand Selection- A Study on Gold Jewellery Consumers of Selected Branded Gold Jewellery Shops in Kerala

US Denim Apparel Market. Denim Exports to EU

The US Jewelry Market Report

Italy. Eyewear Key Figures 2016

Liberalization of Textiles and Clothing Trade and Evolving Global and Indian Trade Scenario

REPORT TO THE MINISTER OF FINANCE

C. J. Schwarz Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science, Simon Fraser University December 27, 2013.

TO STUDY THE RETAIL JEWELER S IMPORTANCE TOWARDS SELLING BRANDED JEWELLERY

ITC Ethical Fashion Initiative Impact Assessment Karen Walker Autumn-Winter 2017 Order, Kenya: July September 2016

Footwear market in the Visegrad Group countries and the Republic of Croatia

Case Study Example: Footloose

COMPETENCIES IN CLOTHING AND TEXTILES NEEDED BY BEGINNING FAMILY AND CONSUMER SCIENCES TEACHERS

Jute Market Report for September /5-4 th October 2018

Sector: Textile and Clothing. Keywords: Bulgaria, Sofia, Furniture, Clothing and Design sector, Clothing and Textile sector.

INDIAN JEWELLERY MARKET-METAMORPHOSIS INTRODUCTION

A Guide on the Ins and Outs of Bedding

Vietnam Garment & Textile sector Update: Unprecedented developments but the industry is still tied up in a knot

Export Success and Industrial Linkages

A STUDY OF DIAMOND TRADE VIS.-À-VIS. GEMS AND JEWELLERY TRADE AND TOTAL MERCHANDISE TRADE OF INDIA DURING THE LAST DECADE

Agricultural Outlook Forum 2003 Presented: Friday, February 21, 2003 RETHINKING COTTON PROMOTION

Understanding Productivity in Pakistani Garments (Pilot Project)

Multifiber Arrangement

US Denim Jeans Market Report

THE PERMANENCE OF SCARRING, VISIBILITY AND COSMETIC DEFECT

PROFILE BUYING OFFICE IN TIRUPUR, INDIA H T T P : / / W W W. T H E S Y N E R G. C O M S A L E T H E S Y N E R G. C O M

APPAREL, MERCHANDISING AND DESIGN (A M D)

COMPANY PROFILE. For Wholesale & Distribution: Reflex Holding FZCO P.O. Box Dubai, (U.A.E.)

Agenda is subject to change. ECV International reserves the right to alter this agenda.

Critical Thinking & Common Core!

T E X T I L E S & A P PA R E L S

PVC FACT BOOK Edition VINYL ENVIRONMENTAL COUNCIL (VEC)

Transcription:

The Antebellum Tariff: Different Products or Competing Sources? A Comment on Irwin and Temin C. KNICK HARLEY Doug Irwin and Peter Temin offer a welcome study of the tariff and American industrialization. Although largely overlooked, the tariff significantly influences our interpretation of early American industrialization. If the tariff had no substantial effect, as Irwin and Temin argue, we view early American industrialization quite differently than if the tariff induced industrialization by diverting trade to otherwise noncompetitive firms within a customs union, as I believe. Although I welcome attention to the tariff, I feel that Irwin and Temin s argument rests on a misconception of the British cotton industry and of the nature of potential competition between American and British cloth in the absence of protection. They find a muted relationship between domestic production and import prices... due to the fact that the product mixes of domestic and foreign producers were quite different... [so] that there were limited opportunities to substitute the products for one another in consumption.... 1 Much of their discussion focuses on the nearly imperceptible decline in growth of American textile production following the dramatic duty reduction in the 186 Walker Tariff. Regression analysis systematically supports the impression from 186 that tariff reduction would have little effect on the American cotton industry. However, all the data come from periods of substantial protection. Even the post-186 rate of 25 percent allowed American mills with processing costs more than 50 percent above those of British firms to undersell British cloth in the American market, because raw cotton made up more than half the cost of plain cloth. 2 Because there are no observations at low levels of protection, assessing the effect of tariff withdrawal involves inference outside the sample range and must be done with care. Irwin and Temin conceive of the threat from imports in terms of competition between two distinctly different goods. If this adequately represents the historical situation, the regression parameters they obtain provide estimates of the consumers elasticity of substitution between the quite different goods. Irwin and Temin can then reasonably calculate the change in consumption from modest change in relative prices caused by tariff removal. 3 Mark Bils and I analyzed competition between American cloth and British imports from a different perspective. Irwin and Temin dismiss our conclusions, which are based on calculations of relative prices and costs, arguing that we miss the evidence that imported British textiles and domestically produced cloth were far from perfect substitutes. This statement identifies the crux of our disagreement. Let me outline the model of competition that I have in mind and the evidence that convinces me that it is a much better basis of analysis than Irwin and Temin s model of competition between quite different goods. Within my view, Irwin and Temin s regression results are hardly surprising but provide little information on which to estimate the effect that deeper tariff cuts would have had. The Journal of Economic History, Vol. 61, No. 3 (Sept. 2001). The Economic History Association. All rights reserved. ISSN 0022-0507. C. Knick Harley is Professor, Department of Economics, University of Western Ontario, London, Ontario N6A 5C2, Canada. E-mail: charley@uwo.ca 1 Irwin and Temin, Antebellum Tariff, p. 791, my emphasis added. 2 This figure arises from the fact that raw cotton costs made up about 60 percent of the price of American coarse cotton cloth. The tariff would be levied on the somewhat lower British cost (see Harley International Competitiveness, table 2, p. 570). 3 As the reader will see I raise some technical problems with the regression results at points in the following discussion. These, however, are minor issues in my disagreement with Irwin and Temin s results. Irwin and Temin, Antebellum Tariff, p. 793. 799

800 Harley TABLE 1 BRITISH COTTON CLOTH EXPORTS: QUANTITIES AND AVERAGE VALUES, VARIOUS DESTINATIONS, 1837 1860 (5 year averages) British Export Export to United States U.S. / Total Exports to United States (000 yds.) Exports (000 yds) IndiaBrazil U.S. / India Exports (000 yds.) U.S. / Brazil 1837 181 26.3 36.9 1.0 33 107 1.3 71 1.57 182 186 19.9 32.6 1.56 26 21 1.82 77 1.69 187 1851 18.0 2. 1.36 81 261 1.56 100 1.37 1852 1856 16.9 21.7 1.28 16 3 1.55 126 1.29 1856 1860 17.1 20.9 1.22 190 707 1. 15 1.19 Notes: All prices are average export value in pence per yard. Export volumes are in thousands of yards. The observation for Brazil in 1853 is missing. Source: Sandberg, Lancashire in Decline, appendix D, pp. 252 62. Bils and I draw on models of international trade in differentiated products. These models rest on a Ricardian perception of trade in which countries differ in their levels of technology but relative advantage differs over different varieties of goods. In equilibrium, the country with the low cost of production for a particular variety supplies all the products of that particular type. The other country will not produce that particular variety of good but will have an advantage in other varieties that it too will provide globally. If the differentiated goods are similar they will be classified as products of the same industry and crosshauling occurs. 5 Nonetheless, imported and domestically produced varieties will be different. Introducing tariff protection stimulates domestic production to the exclusion of imports of some product varieties. These now domestically produced goods will be cheaper behind the tariff than identical imports that have paid duty; and high-cost, protected domestic manufacturers will displace low-cost foreign goods. Imports, of course, will still consist of different varieties than domestic production. However, because the protected industry cannot compete in markets outside its customs union, foreigners will produce identical goods for consumption in the rest of the world. Irwin and Temin s assertion that all the British industry s products differed significantly from the cloth made in America is central to both their analysis and their criticism of Bils and myself. The assertion, however, reflects a misunderstanding of the British industry. Their perception seems to rest primarily on descriptions of British goods imported into America. But, as the Ricardian model suggests, the mix of British goods imported into America was strongly influenced by the tariff. Certainly the British industry made fine goods, laces, embroidery, and the like 6 not made in America (because the tariff was not high enough). The high American tariff confined British imports to these categories while protecting simpler goods. The tariff on simpler goods completely excluded imported goods of this type from the American market ( redundant protection ). Irwin and Temin seem to 5 In equilibrium there may be a few goods on the margin that are both domestically produced and imported. In much of modern literature cost advantages are seen as arising from economies of scale and endogenous technological change in particular products. Thus, for example, America imports Volvos and exports Ford Explorers. See Grossman and Helpman, Technology and Trade for an overview of the relevant theory. Temin, Two Views ; and Harley and Crafts, Simulating use a similar model in a different context. 6 Irwin and Temin, Antebellum Tariff, p. 792.

Comment on Irwin and Temin 801 6,000 5,000 Number Employed,000 3,000 2,000 1,000 0 10-1 20-2 30-3 0-50- 5 60-6 70-7 80-8 90-9 100-110- 120-130- 10-150- 160-170- 180- Average Count Spun FIGURE 1 SPINNING EMPLOYMENT BY AVERAGE COUNT OF YARN SPUN: LANCASHIRE/CHESHIRE REGION, 1833 Source: Great Britain, House of Commons, Factory Inquiry Comission, Supplementary Report, pp. 119 23. feel that the presence of imports of British textiles of any kind even in the periods of very high tariffs in the 1830s and early 180s precludes redundant protection ; but because textiles were differentiated products, imports of some varieties coexisted with redundant protection for others. Irwin and Temin s claims that there was virtually no overlap in the counts spun in the two countries and that Britain was not exporting to other markets large quantities of lower count goods that American producers had specialized in are mistaken. 7 Table 1 provides information about British cotton-cloth exports generally, to the United States, and to India and Brazil two large markets for low-quality cloth. As the Ricardian model predicts, exports to the United States were high-value goods as indicated by a much higher average value than exports generally or to India and Brazil. Contrary to Irwin and Temin s assertion, the British industry supplied large export markets for lower-quality cloth. By the early nineteenth century British exports had almost completely eliminated Indian exports (the coarse cloth against which Francis Lowell sought protection) in third markets and had captured a large market within India itself. British firms sold large amounts of cloth in India and, even after the American 186 tariff reduction, the value per yard was about two-thirds of that shipped to America. Brazil, with its large slave population, provides a second large example. It is difficult to get a complete quantitative picture of the product mix of the British cotton industry in the second quarter of the nineteenth century. Differentiation is most easily illustrated in terms of the fineness of the cotton yarn (the count ) but certainly had other dimensions as well complexity of weave and finish, color, style, novelty, and so on. The best available data on the range of products come from a survey of mills around Manchester for the 1832 Parliamentary Factory Inquiry Commission. 8 The survey indicates the 7 Ibid., pp. 791 and 792, respectively. 8 British Parliamentary Papers, 1833 XX, Supplementary Report, pp. 119 23.

802 Harley count of yarn spun and employment for 151 mills. The mills sampled tended to be larger and more urban than typical of the industry and consequently the survey over-sampled finespinning firms relative to coarse. Nonetheless the data illustrate the range of British production. Figure 1 summarizes the report s information on employment in spinning classified by count of yarn spun. 9 Lancashire mills produced a wide range of counts: from 200 and a little above reported by large mills to below ten. It is obvious that the production did not have a tightly clustered unimodal distribution. The mean of the counts weighted by spinning employment is 70, the median, 0, and the mode falls in the upper 30s. Contemporaries talked of three branches of the industry, which are apparent in the figure. Yarn counts in the 0s and lower were referred to as coarse spinning in Lancashire by the 1830s. These yarns were used in ordinary cloth a pair of jeans uses yarn of a count a little below 20, a man s fine dress shirt uses yarn of 0 to 60 count. Fine spinning referred to counts above 100 and was substantially a separate industry. The output of these mills was doubled into thread for sewing, hosiery, and lace. The third, intermediate group made fine cloth (muslins in British, but not American terminology). We have no similar survey of the American industry, but the distribution of counts of yarn spun was certainly lower, more concentrated and more symmetric. Few yarns of counts above 0 were produced. The mode and the median of the American distribution were both probably in the low or mid-20s counts. Throughout the nineteenth century American consumers purchased British cotton goods in the fine and intermediate categories. Tariff changes affected the purchase of these goods, which satisfied quite different wants than lower-priced goods, only in so far as consumers chose to purchase more or fewer in response to the tariff s effect on price. Changes in their imports had little effect on American production. Irwin and Temin s discussion accurately represents this situation and to a large extent their regression results indicate the limited competition between these goods and American coarse goods. This competition, however, is peripheral to the effect of tariff protection on the American cotton industry. The main issue is how much of the coarse spinning market in which the 25 percent tariff of 186 was still prohibitive would British firms have captured if the United States had not maintained tariff protection? I attempted to address this question in my 1992 article by comparing the selling prices of two well-specified and comparable cloths in Britain and America. One was a printing cloth woven from 30-count yarn toward the fine end of the distribution of cloth made in America. The other was a domestic made with yarn of about 20 count about the modal American cloth. Both cloths were representative of production in both Britain and America. Although Irwin and Temin assert that the British did not produce this type of cloth, both the quotations I use are prices that the Economist reported weekly to indicate trends in the British textile market. British prices of both the cloths were significantly below American prices but the tariff made American cloth cheaper for American buyers. The tariff was overwhelmingly redundant for both the cloths before the 186 revision. After 186 the duty remained high enough to make the American cloths cheaper than imports. Consequently, there was no incentive for Americans to switch to British cloth and American production was only slightly affected by the reduction in duty. However, if the tariff had been removed, British cloth would have been significantly cheaper than the American and a dramatic switch of American purchases from American cloth to the now cheaper, identical, imported cloth would have occurred. 10 9 von Tunzelman, Steam Power, p. 183, presents a similar figure. 10 Harley, International Competitiveness, pp. 565 68.

Comment on Irwin and Temin 803 Of course, in the 180s the American industry had a massive installed capital base. The price of imported cloth would still have covered the variable costs of continuing to operate the existing American factories. As a result, although the industry would have suffered acute distress (and would have pleaded with almost certain success for restoration of protection) it would have continued to produce an approximately unchanged quantity of output until the existing plant became unprofitable to operate. 11 New investment and the industry s growth, however, would have ceased. Bils s and my view rests on the fact that the British produced cloth that competed directly with American cloth but was excluded by the tariff. Eliminating the tariff would have made high-quality textiles relatively cheaper for consumers who would have adjusted consumption, the main impact, however, would have come from buyers shifting purchases from American-produced coarse textiles to now-cheaper identical British goods. The movement of the average value of British exports to America after the Walker tariff shows this happening (see Table 1). In the early 180s the average value of a yard of British cloth shipped to America was more than 50 percent higher than the average of British exports and 80 percent more than the average of cloth shipped to India. By the late 1850s cheaper types of cloth were finding markets in America. The average piece of cloth shipped to America exceeded the average British export value by less than a quarter and the average export to India by less than 50 percent. 12 Irwin and Temin s regression results fail to provide useful information about the vulnerability of the American cotton-textile industry to British competition because their analysis revolves around American consumers switching between two quite separate goods, coarse American textiles and higher-quality imported textiles, as prices changed. This substitution can reasonably be seen as occurring continuously, and estimates from data with the tariff provide useful guidance. This type of substitution, however, is not the process that would have threatened the American industry. We completely agree that the British advantage was greatest in fine varieties of textiles and that the advantage fell as quality was reduced. The New England textile industry followed a general pattern in its competition with Britain. The Americans, like other follower textile producers, were best at coarse textiles that utilized their advantages in cheap power and somewhat cheaper raw cotton and where their technological and labor-skill disadvantages were least. In the late nineteenth century new, low-wage, textile industries in the American South and in Asia revealed similar comparative advantage as they first displaced low-count production, and as they increased technical prowess gradually gained 11 These same short-run considerations also came into force after 186 limiting the decline of output in response to the tariff reductions (see Harley International Competitiveness, p. 568). Consequently, Irwin and Temin s regression results probably underestimate the long-run effects of the tariff reduction. 12 These price observations raise an important technical issue for Irwin and Temin s regressions that take the average value of British exports to America as an exogenous indication of prices in Britain. The type of goods that could be sold successfully over the tariff influenced average value and introduces a bias towards finding little influence of import price on production into their regression results. When the tariff was increased, in say 182, the average value of British exports to the United States would increase because the lowest-quality imports of the previous period could not compete over the new tariff. The regression would observe the quantity increase in American production but attribute it to an exaggerated increase in British price, indicating insensitivity to price. Of course, the opposite happened after 186 with the same econometric consequences. Production was curtailed but the regression, by using a partially endogenous price, associated it with a larger price decrease than is warranted. This criticism of Irwin and Temin s conclusions, however, strikes me as distinctly second order because, even if this problem had been avoided, their regressions could offer very little information about the crucial issue of production-cost differentials in lower-count cloth fully protected by the tariff even after 186.

80 Harley market share by displacing New England and British producers, respectively, gradually in higher-quality goods. 13 Tariffs enhanced high-wage New England s position in coarse cloth but were insufficient to exclude high-count goods. At progressively lower tariff rates, British producers could have supplied American markets with progressively lower-quality textiles (which the Americans produced behind the tariff wall) at prices below the American cost of production. As tariffs fell, the substitution of imports for American cloth would have occurred as a series of more or less discrete shifts, not as a gradual process. When the cost of an imported variety of cloth, including the tariff, fell below the cost of the American equivalent, consumers would have shifted to the now-cheaper British good. For each variety the process would have occurred quite suddenly at the crucial tariff rate. So long as the American good was cheaper Americans did not purchase imports. As soon as the import was cheaper, the American good lost its market unless it could reduce its costs. The tariff rates at which the shift would occur depended on British relative cost advantages for different textile varieties. The magnitude of the shift depended on the American market for that particular type of textile. Irwin and Temin s regressions provide little or no information about how this process might have occurred because all the historical data come from periods when most of the types of textiles consumed in American received high-enough tariff protection to make imports more expensive than domestically produced goods. Tariff and relative cost variations failed to affect American production because the tariff remained high enough to insulate the American producers of most goods that Americans consumed (the tariff was redundant). International price and cost comparisons, as Irwin and Temin remark, are tricky undertakings. Nonetheless, they provide much better insights into the impact of tariff protection on the American cotton industry than Irwin and Temin s regressions. To be sure, comparative and not absolute advantage determines trade flows. and cost comparisons will miss general-equilibrium adjustments to a changed tariff regime. Even though American costs exceeded British prices in the 180s, the American industry might have survived repeal of the tariff if prices of factors employed in the industry fell in response. If, for example, New England labor had been sufficiently immobile, tariff removal might have caused New England wages to fall enough to support continued cotton-textile production. Although this type of factor immobility and factor price response would be missed by price and cost comparisons, the calculations indicate the extent of the changes required. A history of actual tariff removal would reveal the general equilibrium effects, but regressions based on responses in periods of relatively high tariffs cannot be expected to provide much information to their extent. We still cannot assess the importance of the tariff to American industrialization with complete confidence. While Irwin and Temin suggest that the tariff had little impact, their conclusion rests on an unrealistic perception of the competition between British and American textiles. More realistic analysis suggests that the tariff had a central importance. Perhaps the American cotton industry could have survived the removal of the tariff in the antebellum years, but it would have done so only if the removal of the tariff resulted in a considerable fall in wages or in the return to capital in New England. 13 See Wright, Old South, pp. 129 37. REFERENCES Bils, Mark, Tariff Protection and Production in the Early U.S. Cotton Textile Industry. This JOURNAL, no. (198): 1033 5.

Comment on Irwin and Temin 805 Great Britain, House of Commons. Factory Inquiry Commission: First Report, Employment of Children in Factories. Parliamentary Papers 1833 XX (Reprinted Irish University Press Series of British Parliamentary Papers, Industrial Revolution: Children s Employment 3). Grossman, Gene M., and Elhanan Helpman. Technology and Trade. In Handbook of International Economics, Vol. III, edited by Gene M. Grossman and Kenneth Rogoff, pp. 1279 337. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, 1995. Harley, C. Knick. International Competitiveness of the Antebellum American Cotton Textile Industry. This JOURNAL 52, no. 3 (1992): 559 8. Harley, C. Knick, and Nicholas Crafts. Simulating the Two View of the British Industrial Revolution. This JOURNAL 60, no. 3 (2000): 819 1. Irwin, Douglas A., and Peter Temin. The Antebellum Tariff on Cotton Textiles Revisited. This JOURNAL 61, no. 3 (2001): 777 98. Sandberg, Lars G. Lancashire in Decline: A Study in Entrepreneurship, Technology, and International Trade. Columbus: Ohio State University Press, 197. Temin, Peter. Two Views of the British Industrial Revolution. This JOURNAL 57, no. 1 (1997): 63 82. von Tunzelman, G. N. Steam Power and British Industrialization to 1860. Oxford: Clarendon, 1978. Wright, Gavin. Old South, New South: Revolutions in the Southern Economy since the Civil War. New York: Basic Books, 1996.