Using firm-level data to study growth and dispersion in total factor productivity

Similar documents
Table A1. Number of observations by country and year Baseline model: participation in a demonstration

Growth and Changing Directions of Indian Textile Exports in the aftermath of the WTO

SALES (EURO 7.94 BLN) AND TRADE SURPLUS (EURO 2.3 BLN) FOR

CBI Trade Statistics: Jewellery

Textile Per Capita Consumption

Footwear market in the Visegrad Group countries and the Republic of Croatia

The WWI Trade Shock and the Boom of Textile Industry in China

10 TRUTHS ABOUT ITALIAN COMPETITIVENESS FOCUS ON THE BOATBUILDING SECTOR

Comparison of Women s Sizes from SizeUSA and ASTM D Sizing Standard with Focus on the Potential for Mass Customization

What is econometrics? INTRODUCTION. Scope of Econometrics. Components of Econometrics

Procyclicality of Trend TFP Reduces Revisions of Potential Output in the EC estimation

Global Handbags Market Report

CHAPTER - III EXPORT PERFORMANCE OF INDIA S GEMS AND JEWELLERY PRODUCTS IN THE GLOBAL MARKET

About the Report. Booming Women Apparel Market in India

WORLD PRODUCTION AND CONSUMPTION OF CERAMIC TILES

Postestimation commands predict estat procoverlay Remarks and examples Stored results Methods and formulas References Also see

ANNUAL GENERAL MEETING 2013 KARL-JOHAN PERSSON MANAGING DIRECTOR

TOOLING & TECHNOLOGY FOR THE ULTIMATE MACHINE. Medical

How do R&D expenditures influence national total factor productivity and technical efficiency?

COTTON VERSUS SYNTHETICS THE CONSUMER PERSPECTIVE. A. Terhaar Cotton Council International, Washington, D.C., USA

Italy. Key Figures 2013

The Economics of Fashion: Status Motives for Conspicuous Consumption

Sector: Textile and Clothing. Keywords: Bulgaria, Sofia, Furniture, Clothing and Design sector, Clothing and Textile sector.

Italy. Key Figures 2011

Study on T/C Economics, Markets and Competition in the EU-MED area (Economic Intelligence)

ITALIAN WOMEN S FASHION IN

Bald Eagle Shavers INSTRUCTION MANUAL

Thailand s Jewelry Industry Overview 2016

9/1/2016. ECON 302, Introduction 1 INTRODUCTION ECON 302

Italy. Eyewear Key Figures 2015

FASHION CONVERSION BENCHMARKING REPORT: 2015

EXPO RIVA SCHUH Expo Riva Schuh is the key international trade event dedicated to the volume footwear sector. For over forty years now, supply and

Wool Market in the Balance: Global Wool Prices, Supply and Demand

The Optical Market: developments, trends and opportunities. Paris, 26th September GfK - Growth from Knowledge

Global Handbags Market

2014Q1 Beauty & Personal Care Products

TO STUDY THE RETAIL JEWELER S IMPORTANCE TOWARDS SELLING BRANDED JEWELLERY

EMERGENTSKY RUSSIA AESTHETIC MEDICINE MARKET REPORT JUNE 2014

2. The US Apparel and Footwear Market Size by Personal Consumption Expenditure,

The European Confederation of the Footwear Industry (CEC) & The Footwear Industry in Europe. December 2018

Storleksmärkning av kläder Del 3: Mått och intervall. Size designation of clothes Part 3: Measurements and intervals

Gathering Momentum. Trends and Prospects for Fine Merino Wool. Balmoral Sire Evaluation Group 2016 Field Day 8 th April 2016

Extension of Fashion Policy at Purchase of Garment on e-shopping Site

*** * *** * ** *** * * *** * *** ***** * *** L'Observatoire europeen du textile et de l'habillement. -A Factual Report -

Turkish Textiles and Apparel Industry

INDIAN APPAREL MARKET OUTLOOK

TURKISH COSMETICS MARKET

Changing Revealed Comparative Advantage: A Case Study of Footwear Industry of Pakistan

The sunbed industry. SCENIHR Public Hearing Luxembourg, April, 12th 2016

The new luxury in beauty

STUDY ON COMMODITY WISE EXPORTS OF GEMS AND JEWELLERY FROM INDIA

Italy. Eyewear Key Figures 2016

Change & Volatility in Employment & Factory of Apparel in Bangladesh after MFA Era

APPENDIX I. ANALYSIS OF THE CURRENT STATE

Statistical Analysis Of Chinese Urban Residents Clothing Consumption

A STUDY ON COUNTRY WISE EXPORTS OF GEMS AND JEWELLERY FROM INDIA

Clothing longevity and measuring active use

TREND ANALYSIS OF SELECTED SEGMENTS OF THE TEXTILE- CLOTHING MARKET IN THE WORLD AND EUROPE: KNITWEAR, INDUSTRIAL TEXTILES, TAPESTRY AND CLOTHING

DIFFERENCES IN GIRTH MEASUREMENT OF BMI BASED AND LOCALLY AVALIABLE CATEGORIES OF SHIRT SIZES

BUSINESS DOSSIER MARKETING CAMPAIGN

Brief Remarks on the China Model of Economic Development

Financial Integration, Productivity and Capital Accumulation

Consequences of CLO Portfolio Constraints *

IRI Pulse Report Personal Care

International B2B exhibition for footwear, accessories, components and materials. Exhibition. #1in Russia

2017 Chinese Home Textile Industry Development. and the Trend Analysis

Pakistan Leather Garments Sector ( )

Chapman Ranch Lint Cleaner Brush Evaluation Summary of Fiber Quality Data "Dirty" Module 28 September 2005 Ginning Date

Brand Icons and Brand Selection- A Study on Gold Jewellery Consumers of Selected Branded Gold Jewellery Shops in Kerala

IRI Pulse Report Personal Care

A STUDY OF DIAMOND TRADE VIS.-À-VIS. GEMS AND JEWELLERY TRADE AND TOTAL MERCHANDISE TRADE OF INDIA DURING THE LAST DECADE

ALASKA GROSS STATE PRODUCT

US Denim Jeans Market Report

Understanding Productivity in Pakistani Garments (Pilot Project)

Comparative Proteomics Kit II: Western Blot Module Quick Guide

CZECH TEXTILE AND CLOTHING INDUSTRY

Machine Learning. What is Machine Learning?

A STUDY ON COMMODITY WISE EXPORTS OF GEMS AND JEWELLERY FROM INDIA

Czech textile TRADITION PERSPECTIVE CZECH TEXTILE AND CLOTHING INDUSTRY

Ukrainian Textile & Leather industry ,1 thsd ,0 thsd ,9 thsd.. Textile industry. Leather&Footwear. Apparel

Please contact Mr. Jason Chow ( Tel: , Fax: for details of upcoming expos.

Overview of Taiwan Textile Industry 2013

Indian Eyewear Industry Report

This document is a preview generated by EVS

ABS Acai Sterols EFA Efficacy Data

C. J. Schwarz Department of Statistics and Actuarial Science, Simon Fraser University December 27, 2013.

IWTO Market Information Review and Outlook

Product price list The minimum order is 20 pieces.

Global Diamond and Gemstone Market: Trends and Opportunities ( ) March 2015

The US Jewelry Market Report

BUSINESS DOSSIER MARKETING CAMPAIGN

Vietnam Garment & Textile sector Update: Unprecedented developments but the industry is still tied up in a knot

Preparing the Gel Box and Pouring the Agarose Gel

The Use of 3D Anthropometric Data for Morphotype Analysis to Improve Fit and Grading Techniques The Results

It is a great pleasure to see so many of you here today. I will talk about last year, but also tell you a little bit about our plans ahead.

Improving Men s Underwear Design by 3D Body Scanning Technology

Force-based Layout of Non-Markovian Temporal Networks

Case Study : An efficient product re-formulation using The Unscrambler

BRAND PRESENTATION Spring Summer 2015 Collection. Made in Italy

Temporary Shocks and Persistent Effects in the Urban System: Evidence from British Cities after the U.S. Civil War. W. Walker Hanlon UCLA and NBER

Transcription:

Using firm-level data to study growth and dispersion in total factor productivity Dany Bahar The Brookings Institution Harvard Center for International Development July 27, 2016 When looking at the evolution of total factor productivity (TFP) in the world in the last decade depicted in Figure 1, one notices two interesting stylized facts. First, the positive average TFP growth that the world experienced before the global financial crisis of 2008 has been reversed: since 2011, average TFP has continuously declined in the World. Second, the dispersion of TFP across countries has also increased since 2010. This deceleration and increased dispersion in aggregate figures must be a reflection of firm TFP dynamics. Using highly disaggregated firm-level data, this note identifies robust patterns regarding TFP levels, growth, dispersion and the relationship between them during the past decade. To study firm behavior, we use data from the Orbis database from Bureau Van Dijk. 1 The database includes complete information to compute TFP for firms in about 30 countries (see Table 1) and 479 six digit NAICS codes, between years 2006 to 2014. The parameters of the production function per country and 3-digit NAICS code were estimated following the methodology put forward by Levinsohn and Petrin (2003) and Wooldridge (2009), and used to estimate revenue-based TFP for each firm and year in the sample. The results are robust to using other TFP estimation methodologies (Figure 2 compares TFP values in the sample across different methodologies). Figure 3 shows the distribution of log TFP for all firms in the sample, overall and by industry, both in 2008 and 2013. The figure reveals that median TFP has dropped across all sectors, while dispersion is persistent and has remained mostly unchanged across all cuts of the sample. When digging into the data, there exists persistent dispersion within narrowly defined sectors within each country, consistent with the findings of Syverson (2004) and Hsieh and Klenow (2009), among others. Table 2 presents statistics on dispersion measures in the dataset. For example, on average, the TFP Thanks to Luis Omar Herrera for excellent research assistant. All errors are my own. 1 This dataset has been employed also by a number of other researchers in the previous years (e.g. Bloom et al. 2012, Fons-Rosen et al. 2013). 1

Figure 1: Total Factor Productivity by year (world distribution) TFP at constant national prices (2011=1).6.8 1 1.2 1.4 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 Source: Penn World Tables 9.0 This figure visualizes the distribution of log TFP for all countries between 2005 and 2014. The horizontal line inside the box represents the median value. The edges of the box represents the values in between the 25th and 75th percentile, while the whiskers edges represent adjacent values. Dots outside the box and its whiskers represent outlier values. The plot is constructed with values from Penn World Tables. 2

Table 1: Countries in Sample Country # Firm-Years Cum Share Spain 2,976,636 0.219 Italy 1,740,781 0.348 Romania 1,605,494 0.466 Portugal 1,552,508 0.580 France 1,523,388 0.693 Ukraine 597,507 0.737 Bulgaria 492,874 0.773 Czech Republic 447,763 0.806 Korea, Republic of 400,374 0.835 Croatia 347,537 0.861 Slovakia 288,979 0.882 Serbia 253,834 0.901 Finland 241,107 0.919 Norway 210,584 0.934 Germany 188,042 0.948 Estonia 141,497 0.959 Sweden 138,683 0.969 United Kingdom 130,669 0.979 Poland 87,146 0.985 Slovenia 74,873 0.990 Belgium 46,412 0.994 Bosnia and Herzegowina 38,687 0.997 Hungary 37,175 0.999 Latvia 2,811 1.000 Taiwan 1,980 1.000 Ireland 1,535 1.000 Austria 553 1.000 The firms in the sample are active in 485 different six-digit NAICS codes 3

Figure 2: TFP comparison using different methods Total Factor Productivity (log) 2013 2 0 2 4 LnTFP (OLS) LnTFP (LP 3 lags) LnTFP (LP 2 lags) LnTFP (Cost Shares) For visualization purposes, the graph excludes severe outliers in the distribution. This figure visualizes the distribution of log TFP for all countries and industries in 2013 using different methodologies. The horizontal line inside the box represents the median value. The edges of the box represents the values in between the 25th and 75th percentile, while the whiskers edges represent adjacent values. 4

Figure 3: Firm Total Factor Productivity Distribution, 2008 and 2013 Total Factor Productivity (log) 2 0 2 4 All Industries Agriculture/Fishing Minning/Utilities/Construction Manufacturing Commerce IT & Finance 2008 2013 For visualization purposes, the graph excludes severe outliers in the distribution. This figure visualizes the distribution of log TFP for all firms in different sectors both for 2008 and 2013. The horizontal line inside the box represents the average value. The edges of the box represents the values in between the 25th and 75th percentile, while the whiskers edges represent adjacent values. Dots outside the box and its whiskers represent outlier values. 5

Table 2: TFP Dispersion Statistics Measure Mean 25th Median 75th Std. Dev. IQ ratio 2.12 1.59 1.89 2.35 1.09 99th-Median ratio 6.99 2.83 3.97 6.42 30.22 90th-10th ratio 5.58 2.66 3.80 5.95 9.75 95th-5th ratio 13.98 4.01 6.56 12.29 63.93 interquartile (IQ) ratio in the sample is 2.12, implying that the firm in the 75th percentile in the TFP distribution is more than twice as productive as the firm in the 25th percentile. Similarly, the firm in the 99th percentile of the TFP distribution is about seven times more productive, on average, than the median firm of the distribution. Similarly, the figures for the 95th to 5th percentile is 14. It is worth mentioning that these ratios are reduced significantly, almost by half, when limiting the sample to manufacturing industries only, implying that productivity dispersion among service firms is larger. What causes TFP dispersion? Naturally, given that firms are heterogenous agents, we expect them to have different levels of productivity, based on idiosyncratic characteristics of the firms themselves. It is worth mentioning that since our TFP is revenue-based, within industry price differences (i.e. driven by quality, for example) would also explain some TFP dispersion. Yet, if knowledge diffuses easily, one would expect a convergence effect: firms with low baseline TFP levels will tend to grow faster than firms in the upper end of the TFP distribution. In the absence of this linear relationship, we would expect that differential patterns of TFP growth could explain divergence, too. To shed light on this argument, I present the results of transition matrix for TFP using data for 2008 and 2013 in Table 3. Each cell in the table represents the probability of a firm being in quintile q 2008 of the TFP distribution in year 2008 (in each row) transitioning to quintile q 2013 of the TFP distribution in year 2013 (in each column). For instance, the first row of the table implies that, of all the firms that in 2008 were in the bottom quintile of the TFP distribution, about 55% of them stayed in the same quintile in 2013, 25% transitioned to the second quintile, 13% to the third quintile, 9% to the fourth quintile and 8% to the fifth quintile. Naturally, the diagonal elements of the matrix are high, implying that firms in the sample tend to remain in the same quintile of the TFP distribution, particularly for those firms in the bottom and in the top of the distribution (with a probability of 0.55 and 0.45, respectively). In short, the table suggests that mobility along the TFP distribution over time is limited. To control for possible confounding factors related to across firms prices, country-level or industry-level variables, I run a number of TFP growth regressions which control for country-year and product-year fixed effects (products are defined as six digit NAICS codes). The dependent variable in this setting would be the growth rate in TFP for the same firm between two points in time in the sample, and thus, if pricing and quality remains stable within the firm, then growth rates would reflect only changes in productivity. In order to understand 6

Table 3: TFP Transition Matrix 2013 1 2 3 4 5 2008 1 0.55 0.25 0.13 0.09 0.08 2 0.23 0.36 0.25 0.15 0.09 3 0.10 0.22 0.31 0.25 0.14 4 0.06 0.11 0.21 0.32 0.24 5 0.05 0.06 0.09 0.19 0.45 Table 4: TFP Growth Regression Dependent Variable: TFP Growth Rate (CAGR) 3 years 5 years (1) (2) (3) (4) lntfp -0.1498-0.3489-0.0967-0.1991 (0.023)*** (0.047)*** (0.019)*** (0.038)*** lntfp_sq 0.0527 0.0268 (0.008)*** (0.006)*** N 1795333 1795333 774351 774351 r2 0.07 0.09 0.16 0.18 All columns include country-year and product-year fixed effects. Standard errors clustered at the country and product level are presented in parenthesis. p < 0.10, p < 0.05, p < 0.01 whether there are non-linearities in the relationship I allow for a quadratic term in TFP baseline values. The results are presented in Table 4. Columns (1) and (3) present the results of a linear growth regression, which is consistent with the initial intuition: firms with higher initial levels of TFP would tend to grow slower (hence, the negative estimator). Columns (2) and (4) allow for a quadratic term, and interestingly enough, the estimator for such term is positive and statistically significant. This implies that there exists a non-linear, U-shaped, relationship that describes TFP convergence (see Figure 4). That is, firms in the upper end of the TFP distribution would grow faster than those in the middle. This result, by definition, implies quite the opposite: divergence. That is, firms in the lower end of the distribution are able to "catch-up" to firms with average TFP, but these average firms won t catch up with those in the upper end of the distribution, thus generating dispersion in TFP levels. I study these average trends by dividing the sample into developed (OECD) and developing (non-oecd) countries in the sample. The results are presented in Table 5. Overall, the point estimates suggest that for developed nations the speed of convergence is somewhat slower while the non-linearity is more pronounced, implying that dispersion is more likely to occur. When splitting the sample across all sectors (one digit NAICS codes), the 7

Figure 4: Expected TFP Growth based on initial TFP levels 3 year CAGR 5 year CAGR Density of lntfp 0.2.4.6 Linear Prediction.8.6.4.2 0 Density of lntfp 0.2.4.6 Linear Prediction.5.4.3.2.1 0 1 2 3 4 Initial TFP (log) 0 1 2 3 4 Initial TFP (log) This figure visualizes the expected TFP annual growth (CAGR) as a function of initial TFP level, using firm data for firms between the 1st and 99th percentile of the TFP distribution. The red line represents the distribution of firms based on their initial TFP level. The estimation controls for country-year and product-year fixed effects, where each product is a six digit NAICS code. Table 5: TFP Growth Regression, OECD vs non-oecd Dependent Variable: TFP Growth Rate (CAGR) 3 years 5 years OECD Not OECD OECD Not OECD lntfp -0.2871-0.4855-0.1507-0.2818 (0.025)*** (0.040)*** (0.018)*** (0.036)*** lntfp_sq 0.0415 0.0687 0.0193 0.0328 (0.004)*** (0.010)*** (0.003)*** (0.006)*** N 1367798 427531 587642 186709 r2 0.06 0.15 0.14 0.29 All columns include country-year and product-year fixed effects. Standard errors clustered at the country and product level are presented in parenthesis. p < 0.10, p < 0.05, p < 0.01 8

Table 6: TFP Growth Regression, by sector Dependent Variable: TFP 5-year Growth Rate (CAGR) Agriculture Mining,Utilities,Constr Mnftr Commerce IT & Finance lntfp -0.2749-0.2953-0.1704-0.1527-0.2467 (0.028)*** (0.045)*** (0.029)*** (0.030)*** (0.038)*** lntfp_sq 0.0391 0.0410 0.0186 0.0195 0.0342 (0.007)*** (0.008)*** (0.005)*** (0.004)*** (0.007)*** N 26172 111141 160659 252328 224051 r2 0.27 0.21 0.21 0.15 0.22 All columns include country-year and product-year fixed effects. Standard errors clustered at the country and product level are presented in parenthesis. p < 0.10, p < 0.05, p < 0.01 non-linearity is present, as can be seen in Table 6. Does dispersion matter? Productivity dispersion within narrowly defined sectors is a sign that technology or knowledge is not being diffused across different firms coexisting in the same country. This could be a result of the difficulties of transferring knowledge, which would be intensified in economies with poor labor mobility or lack of competition. Yet, does TFP dispersion matter? The particular causes of TFP dispersion are out of the scope of this note; yet, I explore whether dispersion has any robust relationship to aggregate TFP growth. In order to study this, I compute a number of TFP inequality measures based on firms within each six digit NAICS codes for each country-year combination available in the dataset. 2 These measures of dispersion have no clear relationship between the correspondent average TFP level of a six-digit industry and country combination. This is depicted in Figure 5 that plots one of the measures of TFP dispersion (on the vertical axis) against the average TFP for every country-product combination in the dataset in the year 2010 (the figures are residuals after controlling for country-year and product-year fixed effects). There is no clear correlation in the data: there are country-industry combinations both above and below mean TFP levels with both high and low levels of dispersion. Does dispersion matter for future growth? With this data in hand, it is possible to study the relationship between the average growth rate of a countryindustry combination and its baseline level of TFP dispersion, using regression analysis. The data reveals that, almost across all measures, TFP dispersion is negatively correlated to its future growth, after controlling for baseline TFP levels, as can be seen in Table 7. 3 2 The measures are the relative mean deviation, the coefficient of variation, the standard deviation of logs, the Gini coefficient, the Theil index and the mean log deviation. 3 The results for 5-year CAGR are still negative and statistically significant for most -though not all- dispersion measures. 9

Figure 5: TFP Dispersion Standard Deviation Logs.5 0.5 1 5 0 5 10 TFP (log) All values are residuals after country year and product year FE This figure plots for every country and six digit NAICS code the TFP dispersion (measured by the standard deviation of log TFP) against industry average TFP (computed as a weighted sum of firms TFP, using operating revenue as the weight). The values presented are residuals after controlling for country-year and product-year fixed effects, where each product is a six digit NAICS code. The red lines represent the average dispersion and aggregate TFP in the sample. Table 7: TFP Growth and Dispersion Dependent Variable: TFP 5-year Growth Rate (CAGR) Rel Mean Dev Coef Var Std Dev Log Gini Theil Mean Log Dev Dispersion -0.2301-0.0226-0.0297-0.1947-0.0766-0.0888 (0.059)*** (0.003)*** (0.041) (0.053)*** (0.014)*** (0.032)** lntfp -0.0239-0.0199-0.0275-0.0246-0.0203-0.0225 (0.009)** (0.008)** (0.009)*** (0.009)** (0.008)** (0.008)*** N 1768 1768 1768 1768 1768 1768 r2 0.39 0.43 0.37 0.39 0.42 0.39 All columns include country-year and product-year fixed effects. Standard errors clustered at the country and product level are presented in parenthesis. p < 0.10, p < 0.05, p < 0.01 10

Concluding Remarks The existence of important productivity dispersion within narrowly defined industries has been established in the literature in several settings. The reason behind large TFP dispersion could be a consequence of supply side variables such as distortions of factor prices (Hsieh and Klenow, 2009), differential technology adaption or managerial techniques, or demand side variables such as low within-industry product substitutability (Syverson, 2004). 4 Establishing the causal link between TFP dispersion and growth at the aggregate level represents important empirical challenges. It could well be that as average TFP increases, dispersion tends to decrease (a result that would be consistent with decades long research on economic growth and income inequality). On the other hand, dispersion in TFP levels could play a role in hindering future TFP growth. For instance, if frontier firms grow faster than laggard firms (as evidenced in Tables 4 and 6, as well as in Figure 4), then the latter would be discouraged of investing in innovation and technology adoption. Given that these laggards represent a large mass of firms, then this behavior could hurt overall TFP growth in that industry. This result would be consistent with the U-shaped between innovation and competition documented by Aghion et al. (2005): in the presence of a TFP distribution that is highly skewed towards frontier firms, other firms in the lower and middle part of the distribution would have less incentives to innovate and invest in their own productivity. All in all, the results in this note present an important input to understand the era of secular stagnation: few highly productive firms remain at the frontier of productivity, while there is no full TFP convergence dynamics. This generates large productivity dispersion that could be, in turn, slowing down overall aggregate growth. References Aghion, Phillipe, Nicholas Bloom, Richard Blundell, Rachel Griffith, and Peter Howitt. Competition and innovation: an inverted-u relationship. Quarterly Journal of Economics 120, May: (2005) 701 728. Bloom, Nicholas, Raffaella Sadun, and J. Van Reenen. The Organization of Firms Across Countries. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 127, 4: (2012) 1663 1705. Fons-Rosen, Christian, Sebnem Kalemli-Rosen, Bent E. Sorenson, Carolina Villegas-Sanchez, and Vadym Volosovych. Quantifying Productivity Gains from Foreign Investment. NBER Working Papers Series 18920: (2013) p. 69, Cambridge MA. Hsieh, CT, and P.J. Klenow. Misallocation and Manufacturing TFP in China and India. Quarterly Journal of Economics 124, 4: (2009) 1403 1448. 4 See Syverson (2011) for a review of this literature. 11

Levinsohn, James, and Amil Petrin. Estimating Production Inputs to Functions Using Control for Unobservables. The Review of Economic Studies 70, 2: (2003) 317 341. Syverson, Chad. Product Substitutability and Productivity Dispersion. Review of Economics and Statistics 86, 2: (2004) 534 550.. What Determines Productivity? Journal of Economic Literature 49, 2: (2011) 326 365. Wooldridge, Jeffrey M. On estimating firm-level production functions using proxy variables to control for unobservables. Economics Letters 104, 3: (2009) 112 114. 12